Imbalances in the New Zealand economy - Speech
Reserve Bank of New Zealand
News Release
14 October 2005
Imbalances in the New Zealand economy
In a speech to the New Zealand Credit and Finance Institute today, Reserve Bank Governor Alan Bollard said very strong household spending was a common factor in the widening current account deficit and the inflationary pressures facing the New Zealand economy.
Dr Bollard said the Bank's task of maintaining inflation within the 1 to 3 per cent target band on average over the medium term was particularly challenging because of household spending, oil price rises, and the prospect of a more expansionary fiscal policy.
While these factors were adding to inflationary pressures, the current account deficit had also widened as a result of strong domestic demand and the high level of spending on imports that was resulting from the strong exchange rate.
Dr Bollard acknowledged the New Zealand economy had grown strongly over the past four years.
"While a sustained expansion in economic activity is obviously pleasing, we have also seen some significant 'excesses' develop in the economy," he said. Productive resources remained severely stretched, resulting in ongoing inflation pressures and a widening in New Zealand's current account deficit.
"These two developments largely share a common underlying driver - very strong growth in spending, particularly by the household sector, much of which has been debt-financed," he said.
Dr Bollard said many households were funding their consumption by 'unlocking' the equity in their houses, as house values had risen sharply and effective mortgage rates had remained relatively low, due to strong competition among loan providers, low international interest rates and a strong inflow of offshore capital from the European and Japanese markets.
"Households in New Zealand do not actually save anything out of current income but instead dis-save around 12 per cent of income per annum. New Zealand households stand out as having the worst savings record in the OECD area," Dr Bollard said.
He warned that house prices were very cyclical and that the current upward trend would not be sustained. The Reserve Bank has noted several times in the past few years that some households may have had unrealistic expectations in this regard. Household should always consider the downside scenario when making borrowing decisions.
The high exchange rate had also contributed to the current account deficit, by placing pressure on export sector revenues, whilst making imports relatively cheaper. Dr Bollard said the exchange rate appeared to have reached an unsustainable level. Overseas investors in New Zealand dollar instruments should also consider the downside scenario when making their investment decisions.
"At the margin, fiscal policy has the potential to worsen the domestic imbalances. A more expansionary fiscal stance has the potential to aggravate the current account deficit as well as increasing the work monetary policy has to do in order to contain inflation. These pressures will need to be borne in mind as the incoming government considers its fiscal options."
"History tells us that at some point the external deficit will 'correct' back to lower levels," Dr Bollard commented. He said the process of current account correction was likely to involve some combination of an expenditure reduction through lower domestic demand and expenditure switching away from imported goods towards locally produced goods and services. It would also likely to involve an increase in exports.
"For the household sector, which has been relying heavily on mortgage debt to finance spending, this adjustment process may not be painless," he said.
"As far as possible, the Bank will not stand in the way of an exchange rate adjustment, accepting that a short-term boost to tradables inflation may be an unavoidable consequence of adjustment. But the Bank will remain firmly focused on the medium term inflation outlook, which largely means ensuring that domestic inflation pressures are contained," Dr Bollard stated.
The Governor's speech follows…
To view with graphics
see…
http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/speeches/2111459.html
An
address by
Dr Alan Bollard
Governor
Reserve Bank of
New Zealand
Address to the New Zealand Credit and Finance, Rotorua
14 October 2005
1. Introduction
The New
Zealand economy has grown strongly over the past four years.
Initially concentrated in the export sector, this expansion
gradually shifted toward the domestic economy. While a
sustained expansion in economic activity is obviously
pleasing, we have also seen some significant `excesses'
develop in the economy. Productive resources have become
severely stretched, which has led to an increase in
inflation pressures. There has also been a widening in New
Zealand's current account deficit -- the difference between
what the country earns overseas from its exports and
investments and what it pays for its imports and the
investments foreigners have in New Zealand. These two
developments largely share a common underlying driver --
very strong growth in spending, particularly by the
household sector, much of which has been debt-financed.
2. Looking at the imbalances
Figure 1 : Current account deficit reaches 8% of GDP
Some of the drivers of the
recent current account deficit are not necessarily a cause
for major concern. New Zealand has been undergoing a strong
business investment cycle which has necessarily meant high
demand for imports of capital goods, which we can't or don't
produce locally. Investment is obviously necessary for
sustaining future growth in activity. The profits paid on
foreign investment in New Zealand have also been growing,
due to the relative strength of many parts of the
economy.
Figure 2 : Businesses importing capital goods
But while some components of the current account
simply mirror cyclical strength in the economy and the
efforts of businesses to increase their long-term productive
capacity, the widening deficit has also reflected very
strong spending on part of the household sector. At a time
when government and the business sector have increased their
savings (with growing fiscal surpluses and higher profits),
household savings has continued to decline.
During the past few years, we have seen very sharp rises in house prices in New Zealand, reflecting strong demand by New Zealanders and overseas investors alike. Associated with this buoyancy in the housing market has been a strong tendency among many households to `unlock' housing equity built-up through capital gains to fund consumption. This often involves borrowing more against the equity in the home. Rising house prices have boosted the perceived wealth of home-owners and, along with an increased access to debt, have underpinned very strong consumption spending. Strong consumption spending has in turn fuelled much of the demand for imports that has led to a widening of New Zealand's trade deficit.
In effect, we have seen a continued decline in the New Zealand household savings rate -- the proportion of current income that households put aside to invest for future consumption. Statistics New Zealand figures suggest that on average households in New Zealand do not actually save anything out of current income but instead dis-save to the tune of around 12 per cent of income per annum. Of course, there is plenty of room to debate whether this is the most relevant or accurate saving statistic.1 But comparative figures show that, typically, households in most developed countries save at least some of their current income. It is clear that the New Zealand household sector stands out as having one of the lowest savings rates of any OECD country.
Figure 3 : Household credit growing faster than income
It is possible that households'
expectations of the capital gains from housing have been so
strong that many households have seen scope to unlock recent
capital gains, whilst still expecting to be able to build up
their equity sufficiently over the long-run to meet their
savings goals. If so, they would have seen little need to
save anything out of current income. Obviously the success
of this strategy will depend on the extent to which house
prices do in fact continue to rise from here. The Reserve
Bank has noted several times in the past few years that some
households may have had unrealistic expectations in this
regard; indeed a fall in house prices cannot be ruled out.
In Australia house prices today are, if anything, lower than
they were a year ago, certainly so in Sydney.
We are also conscious that there may be subtle changes occurring around what households regard as an acceptable target level of wealth in retirement. This may be driving current consumption and savings decisions. Traditionally, the bequest motive has been a driver of many New Zealanders' savings strategies. Some baby-boomers may be opting to spend more of their accumulated wealth during their lifetime and not make a significant bequest. It is also possible (but hard to gauge) that some households have viewed the recent increase in government savings (i.e. fiscal surpluses) as a sign that they can afford to save less themselves.
Figure 4 : Households consuming from debt
Recourse to debt-financing has been an important part of the process. Despite an Official Cash Rate that has been high by international standards, households appear to have been very willing to increase debt levels to fund their housing and consumption activity. Strong competition among home loan providers -- which has meant lower home loan rates than might otherwise be the case -- has certainly done little to discourage households in this regard. In some cases, interest rates for fixed-rate home loans appear to have been priced below the all-up cost of lending, as lenders have competed for market share. Lenders have clearly seen home loans as a relatively low risk activity and have priced loans accordingly.
Figure 5 : Effective mortgage rate
Household behaviour is not the only influence
on the current account. The rise in the exchange rate over
the past few years has reflected rising commodity prices,
New Zealand's strong relative growth performance and our
correspondingly higher interest rate structure relative to
the rest of the world. The high exchange rate has reinforced
the widening of the current account deficit, placing
pressure on export sector revenues, whilst making imports
relatively cheaper. Although the factors behind the
appreciating exchange are easy to identify, what has been
surprising has been the continued willingness of investors
to continue investing in New Zealand dollars through the
likes of Eurokiwi and Uridashi2 issues notwithstanding a
growing consensus that the exchange rate has reached
unsustainable levels. Over the past year alone, we have seen
an additional $20 billion of such issues, and demand has
continued to remain very strong in recent months. Flows into
these two particular products were larger than was the case
for any other currency.
Figure 6 : NZD since float
New Zealand is not the only country to have
experienced a widening of its current account deficit in
recent years. A number of others, including the US and
Australia have also experienced widening deficits. Strong
household demand has likewise been an important driving
factor behind the increases although, as in the case of New
Zealand, not necessarily the only factor. However, New
Zealand stands out in one important respect. Over time,
current account deficits have to be financed either through
equity investment by foreigners or by borrowing from
overseas. New Zealand's foreign liabilities currently
outweigh its foreign assets to the tune of $124 billion (81
per cent of GDP) a much higher net liability position than
in virtually any other developed country. This reflects our
long history of running current account deficits.
Figure 7 : New Zealand's Net International Investment Position
3. The adjustment process
Currently
standing at 8 per cent of GDP, New Zealand's current account
deficit is at levels that cannot be sustained indefinitely.
Doing so would imply a continued increase in New Zealand's
indebtedness, and debt servicing costs, relative to the
income available to service that debt (i.e. its GDP).
History tells us that at some point the deficit will
`correct' back to lower levels.
The process of current account correction is likely to involve some combination of an expenditure reduction through lower domestic demand and expenditure switching away from imported goods towards locally produced goods and services. It is also likely to involve an increase in exports. Such adjustments are likely to be prompted by a lower exchange rate and/or higher interest rates. The transition to a lower current account deficit effectively means reducing New Zealand's reliance on foreign savings and increasing the saving we do ourselves. For the household sector, which has been relying heavily on debt in order to finance spending, this adjustment process may not be painless. A correction in the housing market -- a slowing in house price inflation or even an outright fall in prices -- is likely to be part of this process.
A reduction in the exchange rate from its current high level is likely to be an integral part of the adjustment process. Significant parts of the export sector, such as manufacturing and services have been under pressure, while those supplying local markets have faced considerable competition from falling import prices. There also appears to be a growing sense among analysts and commentators that the exchange rate is materially overvalued and that a substantial fall is both desirable and inevitable at some stage in the next couple of years.
No one can reliably predict when the exchange rate will decline nor what path it is likely to take. Factors outside our control -- including the path of the US dollar -- could have a significant bearing on developments. It should also be emphasised that even once the exchange rate begins to fall, an increase in exports and a reduction in imports will not occur instantaneously. Export markets take time to rebuild and consumer buying patterns take time to respond to changes in relative prices.
Although projecting when the exchange rate may begin to head lower is a difficult task, the likely precursors for such an adjustment seem clear. As the current account deficit continues to increase, one would expect the foreign providers of capital to re-assess the relative exchange rate risk attached to their investments in New Zealand dollar assets, increasingly recognising that the exchange rate cannot be sustained at current levels. In addition, a slowing domestic economy is likely to see expectations of future returns on such investments being revised down.
4. Why is the Reserve Bank concerned about
all of this?
The Reserve Bank's interest in the current
account deficit, and its associated macro-economic effects,
stems from our key areas of responsibility:
Our role in
helping to maintain macro-economic stability. The Bank is
required to maintain price stability whilst avoiding
unnecessary instability in interest rates, exchange rates
and output; and
Our financial stability role. The Bank
is obliged to make sure the financial system remains
resilient in the face of imbalances (such as a large current
account deficit and growing debt levels) and subsequent
adjustments that might occur.
We will say more about our
financial stability role when we release our next Financial
Stability Report in November. While we believe the New
Zealand financial system is well placed to weather strains
that may be borne by its customers, we will be monitoring
the risks closely as we go forward.
On the price stability front, we are required to maintain inflation within the 1 to 3 per cent target band `on average over the medium term'. That task has been particularly challenging of late due to several factors:
As noted, household demand has remained
very strong over recent times, despite relatively firm
monetary policy settings. Consequently, inflation pressures
have remained strong in many parts of the domestic economy,
including housing and construction.
The recent sharp
rise in world oil prices is putting upward pressure on
inflation as higher petrol prices `at the pump' and the
effects of higher fuel prices risk becoming entrenched in
inflation expectations. At the same time, we are expecting
these increases to exert a dampening effect on household and
business demand. Estimating the balance of these effects is
difficult.
The likelihood of a more expansionary fiscal
policy over the coming period has the potential to add
inflation pressure in what remains a rather stretched
economy. A growing fiscal surplus has clearly made higher
levels of government expenditure affordable in the longer
term. However, in the short-term, a more expansionary fiscal
stance also has the potential to aggravate the current
account deficit as well as increasing the work monetary
policy has to do in order to contain inflation. These
pressures will need to be borne in mind as the incoming
government considers its fiscal options.
We are conscious
that the eventual adjustment of the high current account
deficit could make the job of maintaining price stability
more difficult in these circumstances. In the short-term, an
exchange rate adjustment has the potential to boost
inflation via its direct effect on tradables prices. How
problematic this might be for monetary policy would largely
depend on the timing and magnitude of the exchange rate
adjustment, which is something over which the Bank has
little control. A falling exchange rate in the context of
continued strength in domestic spending would tend to
generate stronger inflation pressures. Conversely, the
inflationary effects of an exchange rate decline that
occurred following a cooling in domestic demand are likely
to be more easily managed.
As far as possible, the Bank will not stand in the way of an exchange rate adjustment, accepting that a short-term boost to tradables inflation may be an unavoidable consequence of adjustment. Clearly, a more orderly and gradual exchange rate adjustment would pose less of a challenge for monetary policy. However, whatever the adjustment path, our job will be to focus on medium-term inflation stability. The extent to which monetary policy will need to continue leaning against domestic inflation pressures will largely depend on the spending and savings behaviour of households.
5. Conclusion
Strong
household demand associated with a buoyant residential
property market has contributed to an increase in inflation
pressures and a widening of New Zealand's current account
deficit. The Reserve Bank remains focussed on ensuring that
the inflation outlook remains consistent with the medium
term target whilst recognising the macro-economic
adjustments that are likely to occur in the face of a large
and unsustainable current account deficit. We are concerned
to see that, as far as possible, such adjustments occur in
as orderly a manner as possible.
---
1 For example, the blurred boundary between households and firms these days might suggest that total private savings, including by firms, is more relevant. Another issue is that saving is measured as the difference between income and consumption, making it prone to measurement error in either of those aggregates.
2 See Drage, D, A Munro and C Sleeman `An update on Eurokiwi and Uridashi bonds', Reserve Bank of New Zealand Bulletin, 68/3, September 2005.